Revisited: Is Social Security Promising Too Much?

A few years ago I wrote a post asking Is Social Security Promising Too Much?, in which I attempted to demonstrate that the average retiree in 2011 could expect to receive a lot more in Social Security benefits than they ever paid in as FICA taxes. This was a retrospective look, so I used annual historical income levels, tax rates and treasury yields going back 53 years in order to calculate how much would have been paid in, how much compounded interest might have been earned, and how much benefit would be paid out based on those contributions. But because current SS tax rates have changed so much since the inception of the program, it recently occurred to me that it might make more sense to look at the question on a prospective rather than a retrospective basis, in order to see if changes to the program have made it any more viable. That is, rather than looking at a current retiree, I decided to look at a newcomer to the labor market, and calculate for various income levels how much the government would collect from them (at current rates) in FICA taxes over a lifetime of working, and compare it to what the SS benefits calculator says they can expect to receive in benefits when they retire, to see if the deal is a net gain or loss to the government.

The calculator actually makes this very easy, since it reports benefits in constant, 2016 dollars, and it assumes a constant income, also in 2016 dollars, from today until retirement day. So we can easily eliminate the complicating effects of inflation and assume a lifetime of constant dollars and no inflation. The last complicating factor is the issue of discounting future cash flows. $100 today is, generally speaking, worth more than $100 at some point in the future, so one would usually use a current interest rate curve to discount all future cash flows back to today in order to get a net present value (NPV) of all the cash flows. While not strictly correct, for the sake of simplicity I used a single discount factor for all cash flows, but I did look at each scenario under different interest rate assumptions.

So, I looked at a single, 22 year old in 2016, just entering the workforce, and assumed a constant income level for his entire working life, until he was 65. Then I ran the numbers on all income levels, in $10k increments, between $10K and $120k (since both taxes and benefits are capped at $118k of income), assuming current tax rates and benefits levels remain unchanged, and assuming 17 years of total benefit payouts (since the expected lifespan of a current 22 year old is roughly 82 years old). Then I discounted all future tax and benefit payments under various interest rate assumptions, to see if the entirety of the transaction from start to finish is a net positive or negative from the government’s perspective.

Below is a table of various income levels, along with both the annual tax receipts and annual benefit payouts associated with those income levels.

Income         Annual Tax @12.4%            Annual payout at age 65
10,000                     1,240                                           8,988
20,000                    2,480                                          12,348
30,000                    3,720                                          15,552
40,000                    4,960                                          18,756
50,000                    6,200                                          21,948
60,000                    7,440                                          25,152
70,000                    8,680                                          26,976
80,000                    9,920                                          28,476
90,000                   11,160                                          29,976
100,000                 12,400                                          31,476
110,000                  13,640                                          32,976
120,000                  14,880                                         34,248

And here is a table of the net present value (NPV) of all tax receipts and benefits paid for each income level at various discount rate assumptions.

Income      1%               2%           3%
10,000    (46,871)    (18,535)     (2,867)
20,000    (37,277)      (3,084)     14,820
30,000    (26,117)     13,309       33,076
40,000    (14,958)     29,702       51,333
50,000      (3,679)      46,167      69,633
60,000       7,480       62,560       87,889
70,000     32,485       87,286     111,185
80,000     60,740      113,968    135,665
90,000     88,995      140,651    160,144
100,000  117,250     167,333    184,623
110,000  145,505     194,016    209,103
120,000  176,048     222,075    234,415

So at first glance this doesn’t look too bad. With interest rates even at just 1%, only those people in the lower half of the income scale would be expected to produce a net lifetime deficit for the government, while those in the upper half would produce a lifetime surplus. And with median income in the US at $52k we can assume a relatively normal distribution both above and below that income level, which means that, again at 1% interest rate levels, the surplus created by the upper income levels should be enough to cover (and even surpass) the deficit created by those at the lower income levels. Yes, this shows that SS is still essentially a wealth transfer program, not only from the young to the old, but also from the well paid to the less well paid. But at least it appears to be financially sound, and a higher interest rate environment only helps matters. With rates at 3% all but the very lowest income levels represent a positive NPV to the government, meaning that most people will be net contributors to, not takers from, the SS pool of benefits.

There is, however, one problem with this analysis. The only reason we discount future cash flows assuming an interest rate is that, generally speaking, a dollar today is worth more than a dollar a year from now because you can take a dollar today and invest it, producing more than a dollar next year. So, for example, at 3% interest rates, I can turn $1 today into $1.03 next year, meaning that $1 next year, discounted at 3%, is worth only (approximately) 97 cents today. An outflow of 97 cents today added to an inflow of $1 next year would produce a NPV of zero.

That being the case the problem with my above analysis is that the government doesn’t invest its revenues. The government simply spends the money that it gets.  From the government’s perspective, a dollar today is worth the same as a dollar one year from now, because the government can’t take $1 today and turn into anything more than $1 next year.  One might argue that the Social Security Trust Fund does invest its excess funds in government securities, but that is an accounting fiction. The “investment” is not made into any wealth generating venture. The only place to do that is in the private market. There is no growth, no new wealth creation, and as a result this “investment” produces zero real growth. So the proper discount factor to use when analyzing SS cash flows from the government’s perspective is, in fact, zero.

That puts the analysis in an entirely new light. At zero interest rates, which again is the real return produced by SS revenues, SS is a huge loser to the government at almost every income level.

Income          0% DF
10,000          (96,572)
20,000          (99,358)
30,000          (99,545)
40,000          (99,732)
50,000          (99,719)
60,000          (99,905)
70,000          (77,096)
80,000          (48,887)
90,000          (20,678)
100,000            7,531
110,000           35,740
120,000           67,748

Only the very top income earners ($100k+) produce a positive NPV for the government, and everyone at every income level up to $60k (ie more than half of the population) produces a negative NPV of nearly $100k per person. Social Security is a horrible deal for the government, and specifically for future taxpayers as they are the ones who will have to cover the ever widening hole that the SS model produces. If I did deals like this for my company, I would be fired in fairly quick order.

That being said, if SS is a bad deal for the government, it must be a good deal for individuals who are on the other side, right? After all, if the government is losing money on the deal, individuals must be making money.  However, unlike the government, individuals could invest their contributions elsewhere if they weren’t forced to pay them into the SS trust fund, so it makes sense from their perspective to discount future cash flows at current interest rates rather than zero. It is true that, a very low interest rate environment, ie one close to zero, it actually is a pretty good deal for medium to low income earners. The NPV of the expected benefits vs expected contributions for incomes of $60k or less is nearly $100k for them. However, as rates rise, the deal quickly sours. With rates of 1%, nearly half of all income earners are under water on their SS deal, and by the time rates hit 2% only the lowest of income earners, those at $20k or less, have a positive NPV. By the time rates top 3%, pretty much everyone is getting less than they could otherwise have gotten.

So it turns out that SS is not only a bad economic deal for the government (ie future taxpayers), it’s even a bad economic deal for most individual recipients in most interest rate environments. So the question lingers: If SS is not viable program from the government’s perspective, and is a bad economic deal from the individual’s perspective, why in the world do we perpetuate this program?

Social Security: Did you know….? 5/17/15

The first Payroll Tax (employee plus employer contributions combined) for old age, survivors, and disability insurance (Social Security) was assessed in 1937 at a rate of 2%. Today’s OASDI tax is more than 600% higher at 12.4%.

In 1966 an additional .7% tax was added to the Payroll Tax for hospital insurance (Medicare). By 2015 that added-on rate had grown by more than 400%, to 2.9%, bringing the full Payroll Tax up to 15.3%, or more than 750% of the original rate.

The maximum income on which the Payroll Tax applied in 1937 was $3,000. In inflation adjusted dollars that would be the equivalent of $49,000 in 2015. The actual maximum income in 2015 is more than twice as high at $118,500.

Doing the math, the maximum annual Payroll Tax amount that anyone in the country would have made in 1937 was $60, or $978 in 2015 dollars. The maximum annual Payroll Tax that anyone in the country actually makes in 2015 is over $18,000.

The expected age at death of a 20 year old in 1937 was less than 70, meaning that the expected SS cost of 20 year old beginning work in 1937 was less than 5 years of payouts. By the time that person actually turned 65 in 2002, his expected age of death had risen to over 80, meaning that the expected number of years of SS payouts had more than tripled to over 15 years.

In 1940 there were nearly 160 workers paying the Payroll Tax for every 1 beneficiary of Social Security. By 1960 that ratio had dropped to 5 workers per beneficiary. By 2010 it was 2.9.

Survivor or not?

From NPR this morning, an interesting question being posed to SCOTUS about survivor benefits from Social Security for children conceived after the beneficiary’s death:

Two eras clash on Monday at the U.S. Supreme Court, when a law written in 1939 is applied to in vitro fertilization. At issue is whether children conceived through in vitro fertilization after the death of a parent are eligible for Social Security survivors benefits.

[snip]

The government concedes the twins are Robert’s biological children. But the Social Security Administration says that it determines eligibility based on the inheritance laws of each state, and in Florida, where the couple lived, children conceived after the death of a parent cannot inherit property, unless specifically provided for in a will.

Karen Capato counters that under the 1939 Social Security Act, survivors benefits go to any child of a covered individual, and the word child is “plainly defined” as the biological offspring of a married couple. She contends that the section of the law dealing with state inheritance statutes only kicks in when the “biological parentage is disputed.”

Is A Baby Conceived After Dad’s Death A ‘Survivor’?

What do you all think?

Mark adds:

The previous post and comments are found at:  https://all-things-in-moderation.com/2011/11/16/do-the-twins-get-ss-survivors-benefits-i-report-you-decide/

Let me add that NPR did a lousy job of presenting the matter.  This is a statutory and not a constitutional case.  The statute requires that the beneficiary must have been dependent upon the deceased individual at the time of his or her death. Citing a case that held that a fetus in esse at the time of its parent’s death had an expectancy of dependency on that lost parent, the Circuit reversed the trial court on the issue of whether these were children, but remanded for a fact finding as to whether they were dependent on their biological father at the time of his death.  I expect a per curiam decision that this is not a contestable fact issue in this case, and a reinstatement of the denial of benefits. There is no way to stretch from a fetal anticipation of support from a parent who dies during gestation to a fetal expectancy of a parent who does not exist at the time of conception.  The Court need not reach the definition of “children”, so minimalism says they should not address that in this case.  I will go out on a limb and say that there is no way these twins can qualify for benefits.

Bits & Pieces (Tues. Evening Open Thread)

Admiral Ackbar Cereal: Your taste buds can’t repel flavor of this magnitude!

QB: You can do real dashes by dropping into HTML and typing — where you want the m-dash to appear. See below.

I also occasionally do music. If you can’t come up with something better to do, then you have to listen to it. Tonight’s selection: I Love You. Although I did it in 2008, the vocal samples are from 1990 or before, and it has a background (it’s like a prequel to I Hate You, a similar-ish song I did at least 3 versions of back in the late 1980s). While I included the link to I Hate You, I might mention that it’s at least 3 minutes too long, and that, perhaps, is charitable.

For the fellas: remembering Bettie Page.

Do you like Daryll Hall and John Oates? Well, I can’t stop listening to this. The Bird and the Bee did a whole album of covers of Hall & Oates. Brilliant! I’m listening on Spotify, rather than YouTube, but . . . worth listening to, if you like your Hall and Oates.

Some people are cynical about the future of Social Security because of the Tuskegee Syphillis Experiment. Well, that’s one reason to be, I guess. — KW



Our fancy dancy new FAQ page is now up and operational. Thanks to all for looking it over and adding to/editting it!
Fairlington Blade, if you show up, I need you to go take a look at it; I need some input from you specifically still. Thanks!

— — Michigoose (OK, Kevin, could you check the HTML and tell me what I did wrong there?)(Nope, still having the same problem. May be the different browsers issue [although shouldn’t HTML code be HTML code no matter what?][and where your mdash is inserted I don’t see the code. Hmmmmmmmmm])

[It apparently converts the code, so I guess you can just copy and paste an M-Dash if you want to, or type one . . . alt 0151 on the PC, option-shift dash on the Mac. Typing format for HTML entities includes the semi-colon: “—” or “–” or “©” (that’s a © symbol) and so on . . . Here’s a list! —KW]

[Yo-ho!! Got it that time! Michi]


Okie, a link to your video (how it would be formatted when writing it in a comment):

<a href=”http://youtu.be/W86jlvrG54o”&gt;This is a tear-jerking video, why am I trying to make people cry before work, I should be ashamed of myself</a>

 Like that. Start with a <a href=”link”>Put something in the middle, then end it with a </a> . . .